翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Free to Fight
・ Free to Fly
・ Free to Love
・ Free to Love Again
・ Free to Move
・ Free to Play (film)
・ Free to Stay
・ Free to Worship
・ Free trade
・ Free Trade Agreement between Mexico and the European Union
・ Free trade agreement between the United States of America and the Republic of Korea
・ Free trade agreements of Canada
・ Free trade area
・ Free Trade Area of the Americas
・ Free trade areas in Europe
Free trade debate
・ Free Trade Hall
・ Free Trade International Bridge
・ Free Trade Party
・ Free Trade Party of Norrbotten
・ Free Trade Union
・ Free Trade Union Committee
・ Free Trade Union Confederation of Latvia
・ Free Trade Union of Workers of the Kingdom of Cambodia
・ Free Trade Unions
・ Free Trade Unions (Bulgaria)
・ Free Trade Unions (Germany)
・ Free Trade Unions (Poland)
・ Free Trade Unions of the Coast
・ Free trade zone


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Free trade debate : ウィキペディア英語版
Free trade debate

Free trade is one of the most debated topics in economics of the 19th, 20th, and 21st century. Arguments over free trade can be divided into economic, moral, and socio-political arguments.
==Definitional issues==
The World Trade Organization (WTO) was created to open up markets and promote international trade based on the 'Free Trade' paradigm. The WTO creates and monitors agreements to reduce trade barriers, and arbitrates in disputes over foreign market access, and violations of these agreements. Its definition of 'Free Trade' is trade ''on a level playing field'', so that the unlimited exchange of goods between countries is ''not'' necessarily 'Free'. If a country with aircraft producers, say, subsidizes corporate research and development (R&D) or enacts regulations requiring the industry to procure its aircraft part suppliers be domestic producers, then the WTO considers this a violation of Free Trade, even when the barriers to trade are not imposed at the national borders in an import-export transaction step (like a tariff).
Some economists argue that a foreign governmental producer-subsidy is another form of "comparative advantage"' and should not be used as a reason to impose domestic barriers on the purchase of overseas goods.
These economists argue that (since the surplus benefit to domestic consumers outweighs the surplus loss of domestic producers) the lower price of foreign subsidized goods is a net positive (as in the standard Ricardian argument) and the source of the "comparative advantage" is irrelevant. Therefore, any import restriction (even on "dumped goods") makes the domestic society as a whole worse off than it would be with unlimited imports.
This "abolitionist" position has had little governmental support in the developed world, due to the following considerations:
* Producer lobbyists and job-protectionists are more organized than consumer advocates.
* The "artificial" handicap of a foreign subsidy seems much less "just" to local production than advantages deriving from geography, natural resources, or native skill. Electorates often prefer "fairplay" to Utilitarian considerations.
* Despite accepting that a country would be better off without tariffs than with them, some game theory models consider that a long-term strategy superior to immediately dropping all tariffs is to negotiate progressively lower barriers bilaterally so as to pry open foreign markets to domestic producers of goods, benefiting both domestic consumers ''and'' domestic producers. (The justification for tariffs is not important; tariffs only exist to be relinquished.)
* If trade barriers are already low, the threat of a "trade war" of tit-for-tat tariff increases may reduce the temptation for either partner in bilateral trade to raise import barriers.
* It would tend to decrease the political power and revenue flowing to government bureaucrats.

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Free trade debate」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.